A Game-theoretical Model of Buy-back Contracts in Assembly
Systems with Uncertain Demand
Zhiqi Lei
Finance major, School of International Education, Wuhan University of Technology, Wuhan, Hubei Province, China
Keywords: Buy-Back Contract, Assembly System, Uncertain Demand, System Coordination.
Abstract: An assembler needs to purchase complete sets of components, each component produced by different
suppliers. Each party in the assembly system shares the risks of demand uncertainty through a buy-back
contract. In this paper, a game-theoretical model is established to analyze how the buy-back contract is
developed under two different mechanisms. The first is one where the assembler sets the buy-back price of
each component, and the second is one where the suppliers set the buy-back prices of their own components.
In both cases, by backward induction, the decision problem is formulated as a constrained optimization
problem. The optimal order quantity is derived. Under the first setting, the system performance is
demonstrated to be increasing in the assembler's share of the profit per unit of product. Under the second
setting, the system performance is demonstrated to be decreasing in the assembler's share of the profit per unit
of product. By comparing the first-order conditions, it is shown that the system performances under the two
settings are equal if the assemblerโ€™s share of profit is larger than the reciprocal of the number of parties in the
system. Finally, numerical examples are provided to illustrate some of the main results.
1 INTRODUCTION
The competition between supply chains has become
the main mode of market competition in the 21st
century. Enterprises in supply chains should
cooperate to maximize the overall benefit. Compared
with the single enterprise, supply chains are usually
faced more demand uncertainties and information
asymmetry, which may lead to the inefficiency of
supply chain. At the same time, each enterprise in the
supply chain pursues the maximization of their own
interests, which may conflict with the overall goal of
the supply chain in the operation process. It has
become a popular research topic to coordinate the
supply chain and improve the profit of the whole
supply chain through well-designed contracts. Supply
chain management is an idea of integration, which
emphasizes the close cooperation of the supply chain
members. However, the supply chain consists of
relatively independent members, whose decision-
making power is decentralized and there are conflicts
of interest among them. The buy-back contract is a
typical coordination mechanism which is widely used
in practice to alleviate the inefficiency of
decentralized supply chain.
In a buy-back contract, suppliers purchase the
product that retailers have not sold out at a specified
buy-back price after the selling season. By
implementing such a contract, the supplier can
provide the retailer a protection, so as to induce the
retailer to increase the order quantity. As the risk of
demand uncertainty is shared by suppliers and
retailers, their revenue and cost are balanced better.
While the retailer can benefit from the buy-back
mechanism, the supplier can also obtain higher profit
from a higher order quantity. Thus, a win-win goal
can be achieved.
In the 1980s, some researchers began to study the
buy-back contract in the supply chain. Paternackde
(Pasternack 1985) studied the coordination of supply
chain where a single supplier and a single retailer sell
a product, focused on the buy-back contract in the
common sales channel, and analyzed the potential
inefficiency of operation due to the influence of
marginal benefit. Under the assumption that the
return price is less than the wholesale price, it is
proved that the total profit of the distribution channel
is similar to that of the vertically integrated supply
chain. His research shows that neither Full Returns
policy nor No Returns policy is effective. A
compromise buy-back contract can promote supply
Lei, Z.
A Game-theoretical Model of Buy-back Contracts in Assembly Systems with Uncertain Demand.
DOI: 10.5220/0011165400003440
In Proceedings of the Inter national Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management (BDEDM 2022), pages 137-144
ISBN: 978-989-758-593-7
Copyright
c
๎€ 2022 by SCITEPRESS โ€“ Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
137
chain collaboration and improve collaboration
efficiency through Pareto optimization. Emmos and
Gilbert (Emmos 1998) and Donohue (Donohue 2000)
pointed out that it is beneficial for suppliers and
retailers to sign buy-back contracts for their trade.
Gong (Gong 2008) showed that the optimal buy-back
contract between suppliers and retailers could not
always be realized under the condition of information
symmetry. In recent years, buy-back contracts have
attracted extensive attention from the academic
community. The effects and design of buy-back
contracts have been studied from different
perspectives (Das, 2017, Giri, 2014, Lau, 1999,
Padmanabhan, 1995, Webster, 2000, Zhang, 2016,
Hou, 2009, Wang, 2008, Xiao, 2008, Xu, 2008, Xu,
2008).
Assembly system is a common operation mode in
modern manufacturing industry (Wang 2003). With
the popularity of industry subdivision and
outsourcing, the supply of components for assembly
lines is often not controlled by itself. Thus, it is
necessary to coordinate the relationship with
suppliers. Due to the characteristics of the assembly
line, the components of the final product are
complementary. It is necessary to coordinate and
manage multiple suppliers at the same time, which
may be difficult. However, few papers have studied
the buy-back contract in an assembly system.
In the context of uncertain demand, this paper
establishes a Stackelberg game-theoretical model for
the buy-back contract of assembly system, studies the
decisions of all supply chain parties, and analyzes the
influence of various parameters on the buy-back
contract. By comparing the system performance
under two different mechanisms, some managerial
insights about the supply chain structure are
provided. In order to facilitate the presentation and
improve the readability of this paper, the following
section first introduces and analyzes the buy-back
contract model in a simple one-to-one supply chain.
2 BUY-BACK CONTRACT IN
ONE-TO-ONE SYSTEM
Consider the following basic case: the demand for the
final product is uncertain, but the probability
distribution is known. The price of the product is
constant. The product is assembled from a set of
components. In order to produce and sell a product,
the order quantities of all components need to be
determined before the demand is realized.
There is only one supplier and one retailer in the
system, and the demand of the product is the random
variable ๐ท , with probability distribution function
๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
, and probability density function ๐‘“
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
. The
supplier and retailer use the common demand
distribution. The retailer has to order the product
before the selling season. There is only one chance to
place an order. The unit cost of the product produced
by the supplier is c, the wholesale price of the product
sold to the retailer is w. The price of the product is p.
Only when the profit is positive, the supplier and the
retailer can be willing to participate in the
game. Thus,
๐‘>๐‘ค>๐‘ should be satisfied. After the selling
season, the retailer can sell the leftover product to the
supplier at a price of b, and one unit of product can be
salvaged at a value v by the supplier. Obviously, ๐‘ฃ<
๐‘ should hold.
The decision variable is the buy-back price b, then
the supplier decides its optimal supply quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌต
,
and the retailer decides its optimal order quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
.
When the buy-back price b is determined, the optimal
order quantity of the retailer and the optimal supply
quantity of the supplier can be calculated respectively
from the classical newsvendor model (at this time, the
case that the optimal supply quantity is infinite can be
ignored. The detailed analysis is given in the later part
of this paper). Obviously, the actual quantity of the
product is the minimum of the optimal supply quantity
๐‘„
๎ฌต
and the optimal order quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
.
For the supplier, the under-storage cost is ๐‘คโˆ’๐‘,
and the over-storage cost is ๐‘+๐‘โˆ’๐‘คโˆ’๐‘ฃ. Then the
optimal order quantity of the supplier satisfies
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌต
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏช๎ฌฟ๎ฏ–
๎ฏ•๎ฌฟ๎ฏฉ
.
(1)
As ๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
is an increasing function, both the
supplierโ€™s expected profit and its optimal supply
quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌต
are decreasing in the buy-back price b.
For the retailer, the under-storage cost is
p
w-
,
and the over-storage cost is
wb-
. Then the
retailerโ€™s optimal order quantity satisfies
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌถ
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏช
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ•
.
(2)
As ๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
is an increasing function, both the
retailerโ€™s expected profit and its optimal order quantity
๐‘„
๎ฌถ
are increasing in the buy-back price b.
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
138
2.1 The Retailerโ€™s Decision on the
Buy-back Price
Now, analyze the principles of buy-back pricing from
the perspective of the retailer. Consider the following
setting: The retailer decides the buy-back price of the
product, and its objective is to maximize its own
expected profit.
No matter how the buy-back price is set, the
supplierโ€™s optimal supply quantity and the retailerโ€™s
optimal order quantity cannot be infinite at the same
time, and at least one of them is finite positive. The
actual quantity of the product is the minimum value
between the optimal supply quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌต
and the
optimal order quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
. If ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
<๐‘„
๎ฌต
, it means that
the retailer has made a lower buy-back price, but it is
not conducive to increase the actual quantity of the
product. It can be inferred that the optimal policy of
the retailer must satisfy ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
โ‰ฅ๐‘„
๎ฌต
. In addition, an
intuitive conclusion is ๐‘+๐‘โ‰ฅ๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ, because when
๐‘+๐‘<๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ, the supplierโ€™s optimal quantity is
infinite.
In short, the supplier will become the bottleneck of
both sides, and the final order quantity is decided by
the supplier. Then this process can be summarized as
follows: The buy-back price is set by the retailer, and
the final order quantity is determined by the supplier.
From the above discussion, the following conditions
can be obtained:
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏช
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ•
โ‰ฅ
๎ฏช๎ฌฟ๎ฏ–
๎ฏ•๎ฌฟ๎ฏฉ
,๐‘+๐‘โ‰ฅ๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ.
(3)
The final quantity of the product is ๐‘„. As the
conditions of ๐‘„=๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌต
,๐‘„
๎ฌถ
๏ˆป
=๐‘„
๎ฌต
and
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏช๎ฌฟ๎ฏ–
๎ฏ•๎ฌฟ๎ฏฉ
holds, the retailerโ€™s profit is
๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐ธ[โˆ’๐‘ค๐‘+๐‘๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘„,๐ท
๏ˆป
+๐‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„โˆ’
๐ท
๏ˆป
๎ฌพ
].
(4)
The above problem can be summarized as a
constrained optimization problem as follows:
๐‘š๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐œ‹
๎ฌต
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ค
๏ˆป
๐‘„
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘
๏ˆป
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๎ฏŠ
๎ฌด
๐‘ .๐‘ก.
๎ตž
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌต
๏ˆป
=
๐‘คโˆ’๐‘
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ค
๐‘โˆ’๐‘
โ‰ฅ
๐‘คโˆ’๐‘
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ฃ
,๐‘+๐‘โ‰ฅ๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ
(5)
The solution and discussion of these equations are
carried out in Section 3.
2.2 The Supplierโ€™s Decision on the
Buy-back Price
Now, analyze the principles of buy-back pricing from
the perspective of the supplier. Consider the
following setting: The supplier decides the buy-back
price of the product to maximize its own expected
profit.
The principle is the same as that described in the
previous subsection. When the supplier decides the
buy-back price, the supplier will set the buy-back
price low enough to maximize its own profit. If ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
>
๐‘„
๎ฌต
, the buy-back price is too high, because it is not
conducive to increase the retailerโ€™s order quantity. In
short, the final quantity of the product is decided by
the retailer. Then this process can be summarized as
follows: The buy-back price is determined by the
supplier, and the final quantity of the product is
determined by the retailer.
The actual quantity of the product is the minimum
between the supplierโ€™s optimal supply quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌต
and the retailerโ€™s optimal order quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌถ
. The
retailerโ€™s optimal order quantity is infinite if ๐‘>๐‘ค.
From the above discussion, the following conditions
can be obtained:
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏช
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ•
โ‰ค
๎ฏช๎ฌฟ๎ฏ–
๎ฏ•๎ฌฟ๎ฏฉ
,๐‘+๐‘โ‰ค๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ.
(6)
The final quantity of the product is
๐‘„. As ๐‘„=๐‘„
๎ฌถ
,
it can be inferred that ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏช
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ•
. The supplierโ€™s
profit is
๐œ‹
๎ฌถ
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐ธ[
๏ˆบ
๐‘คโˆ’๐‘
๏ˆป
๐‘„โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’
๐‘ฃ
๏ˆป๏ˆบ
๐‘„โˆ’๐ท
๏ˆป
๎ฌพ
].
(7)
The above problem can be summarized as a
constrained optimization problem as follows:
๐‘š๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐œ‹
๎ฌถ
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘คโˆ’๐‘
๏ˆป
๐‘„
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๏ˆป
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๎ฏŠ
๎ฌด
๐‘ .๐‘ก.
๎ตž
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ค
๐‘โˆ’๐‘
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ค
๐‘โˆ’๐‘
โ‰ค
๐‘คโˆ’๐‘
๐‘โˆ’๐‘ฃ
, ๐‘+๐‘โ‰ค๐‘ค+๐‘ฃ
(8)
The solution and discussion of these equations
will also be carried out in Section 3.
3 BUY-BACK CONTRACT FOR
ASSEMBLY SYSTEM
The assembler has to buy the components before the
actual demand is known. Due to the uncertainty of
A Game-theoretical Model of Buy-back Contracts in Assembly Systems with Uncertain Demand
139
demand, the assembler need to make decisions based
on demand prediction. The output of the assembly
system is limited to each link, and the output capacity
of the system is equal to the weakest link. In addition,
in order to deal with the risk of demand uncertainty,
the supply chain members may sign buy-back
contracts to share the risk. The benefit of this contract
is to reduce the risk downstream of the supply chain,
encourage them to increase their order quantities, and
thereby increase the overall profit of the system. Due
to the complementarity of components, designing the
buy-back contract of an assembly system is relatively
complicated.
The demand for the final product of the assembly
system is a random variable D. The probability
distribution function of D is
๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
, and the probability
density function is ๐‘“
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
. The unit price of the product
in the market is p. The product consists of n
components. Without loss of generality, suppose that
each supplier produces one of these n components.
For notational convenience, define ๐‘=
๏ˆผ
1,2,โ€ฆ,๐‘›
๏ˆฝ
.
All supply chain parties have to decide the order
quantity or supply quantity before the selling season.
Once the components are in place, the demand is
realized and the product can be assembled in a short
time.
The unit cost of component i is ๐‘
๎ฏœ
. Considering
the assembly process, the production of a final product
also needs to invest ๐‘
๎ฌด
as the assembly cost.
Obviously,
โˆ‘
๐‘
๎ฏœ
<๐‘
๎ฏก
๎ฏœ๎ญ€๎ฌด
is required to make sure
that the profit is positive. In fact, ๐‘
๎ฌด
can be set equal
to zero, and then the market price of the product can
be adjusted to be ๐‘โˆ’๐‘
๎ฌด
. The wholesale price of
component i is ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
, then ๐‘โˆ’
โˆ‘
๐‘ค
๐‘–
๐‘›
๐‘–=1
is the
assemblerโ€™s profit from one unit of the product. To
ensure that each member does not refuse to participate
in the game, ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
>๐‘
๎ฏœ
is required. Because the
demand is random and the ordering decisions need to
be made before demand realization, overstocking or
understocking can occur. The unite salvage value of
component i is ๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
<๐‘
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
.
The decision variable is the buy-back price ๐‘
๎ฏœ
of
each component. Each component supplier shall
decide its supply quantity ๐‘„
๎ฏœ
according to the buy-
back price, and the assembler shall decide the order
quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌด
.
The sum of the corresponding parameters is in
uppercase letters for marking convenience. For
example, define
๐ถโ‰ก๎ท ๐‘
๎ฏœ
,๐ตโ‰ก๎ท๐‘
๎ฏœ
๎ฏก
๎ฏœ๎ญ€๎ฌต
,
๎ฏก
๎ฏœ๎ญ€๎ฌต
(9)
๐‘Šโ‰ก๎ท ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
,๐‘‰โ‰ก๎ท๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
๎ฏก
๎ฏœ๎ญ€๎ฌต
,
๎ฏก
๎ฏœ๎ญ€๎ฌต
Suppliers and retailers use the same demand
distribution. When the buy-back price ๐‘
๎ฏœ
,๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘ is
determined, the optimal order quantity (supply
quantity) of each supply chain party can be calculated
from the classical newsvendor model. The final
quantity of the product and components should be as
follows: The quantity of each component is the same,
and the actual quantity ๐‘„ of the product is the
minimum among the optimal supply quantity ๐‘„
๎ฏœ
๏ˆบ
๐‘–=
1,2,โ€ฆ๐‘›
๏ˆป
and the optimal order quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌด
. That is
to say, ๐‘„=๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆผ
๐‘„
๎ฏœ
๏ˆฝ
.
The profit of the system is
๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐ธ[โˆ’๐ถ๐‘„+๐‘๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘„,๐ท
๏ˆป
+๐‘‰
๏ˆบ
๐‘„โˆ’
๐ท
๏ˆป
๎ฌพ
],
(10)
which can be written as
๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐ถ
๏ˆป
๐‘„โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰
๏ˆป
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๎ฏŠ
๎ฌด
.
(11)
According to the classical newsvendor model, the
above profit function is concave and has a unique
optimal solution. This property can help compare the
effectiveness of different mechanisms.
3.1 A Contract Model in Which the
Assembler Determines the
Buy-back Price
Now, from the assemblerโ€™s point of view to analyze
the principle of buy-back price formulation. Consider
this situation: the assembler decides the buy-back
price of the product, and the assembler's goal in setting
the buy-back price is to maximize its own profit.
Facing n suppliers, the assembler formulates the
buy-back price ๐‘
๎ฏœ
of each component ๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘. The
optimal strategy of the assembler to formulate the
buy-back price should meet the following conditions:
๐‘„
๎ฌด
โ‰ฅ๐‘„
๎ฌต
=๐‘„
๎ฌถ
=โ‹ฏ=๐‘„
๎ฏก
;
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌด
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
,๐‘
๎ฏœ
+๐‘
๎ฏœ
โ‰ฅ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
+๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
,๐‘–๐œ–๐‘;
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
โ‰ฅ
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
;
The supplierโ€™s optimal policy must satisfy ๐‘„
๎ฌด
โ‰ฅ
๐‘„
๎ฏœ
,๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘. If there exists i which makes ๐‘„
๎ฌด
<๐‘„
๎ฏœ
,
then it means that the assembler has set a too low buy-
back price, which is not conducive to increase the
order quantity. In addition, when the buy-back price
is determined, the optimal supply quantity of each
component can be obtained immediately according to
the classical newsvendor model. It is useless for one
supplier to have the optimal supply quantity higher
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
140
than others, which is a waste to the assembler, and the
buy-back price of this component must be increased.
Thus, the optimal supply quantity of each supplier
should be the same. When the sum of the buy-back
prices of each supplier is fixed, the optimal policy is
the one that maximizes the output of the system.
Therefore, the optimal strategy must satisfy ๐‘„
๎ฌด
โ‰ฅ
๐‘„
๎ฌต
=๐‘„
๎ฌถ
=โ‹ฏ=๐‘„
๎ฏก
. In order to ensure that the
optimal supply quantity of each supplier is limited,
๐‘
๎ฏœ
+๐‘
๎ฏœ
>๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
+๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
should hold for all ๐‘–๐œ–๐‘. The
intuitive explanation is that suppliers will pay cost
when their production exceeds the actual demand.
According to the above analysis, the final quantity
of the product is determined by the supplier. Then the
process of the assembler-as-the-leader buy-back
contract can be summarized as follows: the buy-back
price is determined by the assembler, and then the
optimal order quantity is determined by all of them,
and finally the output of the system is determined by
the suppliers.
For supplier i, the under-storage cost is
๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
+๐‘
๎ฏœ
,
and the over-storage cost is
๐‘
๎ฏœ
+๐‘
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
.
Then the supplierโ€™s optimal order quantity satisfies
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏช
๎ณ”
๎ฌฟ๎ฏ–
๎ณ”
๎ฏ•
๎ณ”
๎ฌฟ๎ฏฉ
๎ณ”
.
(12)
It follows that
๐‘ค
๎ฌต
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฌต
๐‘
๎ฌต
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฌต
=
๐‘ค
๎ฌถ
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฌถ
๐‘
๎ฌถ
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฌถ
=โ‹ฏ=
๐‘ค
๎ฏก
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฏก
๐‘
๎ฏก
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฏก
=
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’
๐‘‰
(13)
As ๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
is an increasing function, the larger the
buy-back price ๐‘
๎ฏœ
is, the smaller the optimal supply
quantity ๐‘„
๎ฏœ
and the supplierโ€™s expected profit are.
For the assembler, the under-storage cost is ๐‘โˆ’
๐‘Š, and the over-storage cost is ๐‘Šโˆ’๐ต. Then the
optimal order quantity of the assembler satisfies
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๎ฌด
๏ˆป
=
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
.
(14)
As ๐น
๏ˆบ
โˆ™
๏ˆป
is an increasing function, the larger the
buy-back price B is, the larger the optimal order
quantity ๐‘„
๎ฌด
and the expected profit of the assembler
are.
According to the above discussion, the following
conditions can be obtained:
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
โ‰ฅ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’๐‘‰
,๐‘
๎ฏœ
+๐‘
๎ฏœ
>๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
+๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
,๐‘–๐œ–๐‘.
(15)
The final quantity of the product is ๐‘„=
๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆผ
๐‘„
๎ฏœ
๏ˆฝ
=๐‘„
๎ฌต
, then ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
.
The profit function of assemblers is
๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐ธ
[
โˆ’๐‘Š๐‘„+ ๐‘๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘„,๐ท
๏ˆป
+๐ต
๏ˆบ
๐‘„โˆ’๐ท
๏ˆป
๎ฌพ
]
.
(16)
The expression of the profit function is
๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’W
๏ˆป
๐‘„
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘
โˆ’B
๏ˆป
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๐‘„
0
.
(17)
where ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›๏‰„
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
,
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๏‰….
It follows that
๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
is continuously
differentiable at the point B=
๏ˆบ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๏ˆป๏ˆบ
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๏ˆป
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
+๐‘‰, which
is equivalent to
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
. However, the previous
analysis has shown that the optimal value of B should
satisfy
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
โ‰ฅ
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
. Thus, the problem can be
simplified by narrowing down the feasible region.
The above problem can be summarized as a
constrained optimization problem:
๐‘š๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๏ˆป
๐‘„โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
๏ˆป
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๎ฏŠ
๎ฌด
๐‘ .๐‘ก.
โŽฉ
โŽจ
โŽง
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’๐‘‰
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘
โˆ’๐ต
โ‰ฅ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’๐‘‰
,๐ต+๐ถโ‰ฅ๐‘Š+
๐‘‰
(18)
Here, the inequality constraint ๐ต+๐ถโ‰ฅ๐‘Š+๐‘‰
can be omitted because it can be inferred from the
first equality constraint as follows:
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’๐‘‰
=๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
โ‰ค1.
(19)
The derivative of ๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
with respect to ๐‘„ is
๐‘‘๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘„
=๐‘โˆ’๐ถโˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰
๏ˆป
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๏ˆป
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
.
(20)
Where
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๐‘“
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
[
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
]
๎ฌถ
๎ถฑ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๐‘„
0
.
(21)
If
๎ฏ—๎ฐ—
๎ฐฌ
๏ˆบ
๎ฏŠ
๏ˆป
๎ฏ—๎ฏŠ
is a decreasing function, then the profit
function ๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
of the assembler is concave. The
following properties can also be obtained from the
above derivative function.
Theorem 1. If the buy-back price is determined
by the assembler, then
๏‚ง The output ๐‘„ of the system and the overall
profit ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
of the system are not affected by
the number of suppliers. If
,,CWV
are fixed,
the specific parameter of each supplier does not
affect ๐‘„ and ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
;
๏‚ง ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
and ๐‘„ are increasing in ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
and ๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
,
decreasing in ๐‘
๎ฏœ
;
A Game-theoretical Model of Buy-back Contracts in Assembly Systems with Uncertain Demand
141
๏‚ง When the marginal sales profit ๐‘โˆ’๐ถ of the
product is fixed, the system output ๐‘„ and
profit ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
decrease with ๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ, the profit
obtained by the supplier.
The practical implications of these properties will
be discussed in the next section. In addition, it can be
inferred that the inequality condition
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
โ‰ฅ
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
can be ignored in the process of finding the
optimal solution if
๎ฏ—๎ฐ—
๎ฐฌ
๏ˆบ
๎ฏŠ
๏ˆป
๎ฏ—๎ฏŠ
is a decreasing function,
because the stationary point of the objective function
must satisfy this inequality. This can help to simplify
the process of solving the optimization problem.
3.2 A Contract Model in Which the
Suppliers Determine the Buy-back
Prices
Now, analyze the principle of buy-back price from
the supplierโ€™s perspective. Consider this following
setting: The suppliers decide the buy-back prices of
the components to maximize their own profits.
After the n suppliers determine their buy-back
prices respectively, the optimal supply quantity of
each supplier is determined. Then the assembler
determines the order quantity, which is no higher than
each of the supplierโ€™s optimal supply quantity. The
optimal policy for the suppliers to set the buy-back
prices should satisfy the following properties:
๏‚ง ๐‘
๎ฏœ
โ‰ค๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
;๐‘–๐œ–๐‘;
๏‚ง ๐‘„
๎ฌด
โ‰ค๐‘„
๎ฏœ
;๐‘–๐œ–๐‘;
๏‚ง
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
โ‰ค
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
,๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
.
Each supplier will set a low enough buy-back
price so that the assemblerโ€™s order quantity is no
higher than the supplierโ€™s optimal supply quantity.
That is to say, ๐‘„
๎ฌด
โ‰ค๐‘„
๎ฏœ
,๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘. If this condition does
not hold, the supplier will decrease the buy-back price
so as to reduce its own risk without affecting its
supply quantity. This can be summarized as the
following conditions:
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
โ‰ค
๐‘ค
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘
๐‘–
๐‘
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๐‘–
,๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘.
(22)
According to previous analysis, ๐‘„=๐‘š๐‘–๐‘›
๏ˆผ
๐‘„
๎ฏœ
๏ˆฝ
=
๐‘„
๎ฌด
. The supplierโ€™s profit is
๐œ‹
๎ฏœ
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=๐ธ
[
๏ˆบ
๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
๐‘„โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป๏ˆบ
๐‘„โˆ’๐ท
๏ˆป
๎ฌพ
]
.
(23)
Then the problem can be expressed as the
following constrained optimization problem:
๐‘š๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐œ‹
๎ฌต
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๏ˆบ
๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
๐‘„โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
๎—ฌ
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘ฅ
๎ฏŠ
๎ฌด
(24)
๐‘ .๐‘ก.
โŽฉ
โŽจ
โŽง
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
โ‰ค
๐‘ค
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘
๐‘–
๐‘
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๐‘–
,๐‘
๐‘–
+๐‘
๐‘–
โ‰ฅ๐‘ค
๐‘–
+๐‘ฃ
๐‘–
,๐‘–โˆˆ๐‘
The value of ๐‘„ in the above formula depends on
all
๐‘
๎ฏœ
values, i.e., ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
โˆ‘
๐‘
๐‘–
๎ณ™
๎ณ”๎ฐธ๎ฐญ
๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
, which
makes the problem difficult to solve. The derivative
of the profit function
๐œ‹
๎ฏœ
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
is
๐‘‘๐œ‹
๎ฏœ
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘„
=๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘
๎ฏœ
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘
๎ฏœ
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
๏ˆป
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๏ˆป
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
.
(25)
From the above equation, it can be concluded that
the output of the system satisfies
๐‘โˆ’๐ถโˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰
๏ˆป
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
โˆ’๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๏ˆป
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=0.
(26)
Theorem 2. If the buy-back price is determined
by the suppliers, then
๏‚ง When the parameters C, W, V are fixed,
()
Qp
and ๐‘„ have nothing to do with the specific
parameters of each supplier;
๏‚ง ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
and ๐‘„ are increasing in ๐‘ค
๎ฏœ
,๐‘ฃ
๎ฏœ
, but
decreasing in
i
c
and the number of suppliers
n;
๏‚ง When the unit sales profit ๐‘โˆ’๐ถ is fixed,
๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
and ๐‘„ decrease with ๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š.
As in the assembler-led case, it can be inferred
that if
๎ฏ—๎ฐ—
๎ณ”
๏ˆบ
๎ฏŠ
๏ˆป
๎ฏ—๎ฏŠ
is a decreasing function, the optimal
solution must satisfy the inequality
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
โ‰ค
๐‘ค
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘
๐‘–
๐‘
๐‘–
โˆ’๐‘ฃ
๐‘–
.
Otherwise, it is not optimal. This property can help to
simplify the solution process.
The results in Theorem 2 and Theorem 1 are very
different. In the case that the assembler decides the
buy-back prices, the final quantity of the product has
nothing to do with the number of suppliers, and the
profit proportion of the assembler plays a positive
role in the system performance. In the case that
suppliers decide the buy-back prices, both the number
of suppliers and the profit proportion of the assembler
have negative effects on the system performance.
4 PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS
Sections 2 and 3 discuss two determination
mechanisms of buy-back prices in a decentralized
assembly system and get some results. This section
further compares the system performance (the overall
profit of the system) in different mechanisms.
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
142
4.1 Performance Analysis of
Decentralized and Centralized
Systems
Assume that the parameters of an assembly system
are given, the profit of the system can be calculated
in both decentralized and centralized cases. An
intuitive conjecture is that the profits of centralized
systems are higher than those of decentralized
systems. Next, some analysis is provided to support
this conjecture.
From the classical newsvendor model, the optimal
output of the centralized system satisfies ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
. It should also be pointed out that the profit
function of the classical newsvendor model is
concave. Thus, the profit function is increasing on the
left side of the optimal solution, and decreasing on the
right side of the optimal solution.
In the case that the assembler decides the buy-
back price, the constraint condition (18) implies
several intuitive facts. At the critical point
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
, the system output satisfies ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
, which
is the same as that of the centralized system.
However, by substituting
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
into the
derivative function, it can be obtained that
๐‘‘๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘„
=โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๏ˆป
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
<0.
(27)
The optimality condition of centralized system
does not hold. It is easy to know that the system
output is lower than the case of centralized system.
In the case where the supplier decides the buy-
back prices, the constraint condition (24) implies that
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๐‘โˆ’๐ต
โ‰ค
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๐ตโˆ’๐‘‰
.
(28)
At the critical point
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎป
=
๎ฏ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฎป๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
, ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
holds but the optimality condition (26) is violated.
According to the concavity of the profit function,
it can be known that the system performance of the
two decentralized system is lower than that of the
centralized system.
4.2 Performance Comparison of the
Two Decentralized System
When the supplier decides the buy-back price of each
component, the optimal output ๐‘„ of the system
solves (26). When the assembler decides the buy-
back price of each component, the optimal output ๐‘„
of the system satisfies
๐‘โˆ’๐ถโˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰
๏ˆป
๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
โˆ’
๏ˆบ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๏ˆป
๐œ‘
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=0.
(29)
As described in the previous theorem, in both
mechanisms, the parameters of the system will affect
the final performance of the system. It can be seen
that (26) and (29) are very similar, except that only
one coefficient is different, i.e., ๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š
๏ˆป
and
๏ˆบ
๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
๏ˆป
.
According to Theorems 1 and 2, the output ๐‘„
and the performance ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
are the same in the two
decentralized systems only if ๐‘›
๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰
๏ˆป
=๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ
holds. This equality is equivalent to
๏ˆบ
๐‘›+1
๏ˆป๏ˆบ
๐‘โˆ’
๐‘Š
๏ˆป
=๐‘โˆ’๐ถ.
Let ๐›ฟ=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
. If and only if ๐›ฟ
๏ˆบ
๐‘›+1
๏ˆป
=1, the
system performances in the two cases are the same. If
๐›ฟ
๏ˆบ
๐‘›+1
๏ˆป
>1 holds, the system performance is
better in the case that the assembler decides the buy-
back prices. On the contrary, if ๐›ฟ
๏ˆบ
๐‘›+1
๏ˆป
<1 holds,
the system performance is better in the case that the
suppliers decide the buy-back prices. ๐›ฟ is a
threshold value of the assembly system, to determine
which mechanism is better for the decentralized
system.
In the case that the assembler decides the buy-
back prices, the output ๐‘„ and expected profit ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
of the system are increasing in ๐›ฟ, and not affected by
the number of suppliers. In the case that suppliers
decide the buy-back prices, the output ๐‘„ and
expected profit ๐œ‹
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
of the system are decreasing in
l
, and the number of suppliers.
The parameter ๐›ฟ can be interpreted as the
proportion of the unit sales profit owned by the
assembler. The above results can be intuitively
understood as follows: When the assembler has a
strong market position (strong ability to obtain
profits), the whole system will benefit from the
assemblerโ€™s dominant role in the negotiation of buy-
back prices. On the contrary, when the suppliers are
strong, the whole system will benefit from the
suppliersโ€™ dominant role in the negotiation of buy-
back prices.
4.3 Numerical Example
Here is a simple numerical example to illustrate the
results in the previous subsections. Let ๐‘“
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
=2๐‘ฅ
and ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘ฅ
๏ˆป
=๐‘ฅ
๎ฌถ
, ๐‘ฅโˆˆ
[
0,1
]
. The other parameters are
as follow: ๐‘โˆ’ ๐ถ=100, ๐‘โˆ’๐‘Š=50,
๐‘โˆ’๐‘‰=
150. Then ๐‘Šโˆ’๐ถ=50,๐›ฟ=
๎ฌต
๎ฌถ
.
According to ๐น
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
=
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฎผ
๎ฏฃ๎ฌฟ๎ฏ
, the optimal output of
the centralized system is ๐‘„=0.816. In the
decentralized system where the buy-back prices are
A Game-theoretical Model of Buy-back Contracts in Assembly Systems with Uncertain Demand
143
determined by the assembler, the output of the system
satisfies
๐‘‘๐œ‹
๎ฌด
๏ˆบ
๐‘„
๏ˆป
๐‘‘๐‘„
=
250
3
โˆ’ 300๐‘„=0.
(30)
The solution is ๐‘„=0.278. It is obvious that the
system output and system profit are lower than the
centralized system. In the decentralized system where
the supplier sets the buy-back prices, the output of the
system satisfies
100 โˆ’
50
3
๐‘›โˆ’ 300๐‘„=0.
(31)
Take ๐‘›=2. The solution is ๐‘„=0.222, which
is lower than 0.278. In fact, ๐›ฟ
๏ˆบ
๐‘›+1
๏ˆป
>1 holds in
the above example. Thus, the system profit is higher
when the assembler decides the buy-back prices. In
addition, (31) can be written as follows:
๐‘„=
1
3
โˆ’
1
18
๐‘›.
(32)
Obviously, ๐‘„ is a decreasing function of n, and
so is the profit of the system. This is consistent with
the theoretical result in the previous section.
5 CONCLUSIONS
The purpose of this paper is to explore the principle
of designing the buy-back contract for the assembly
system. Between the supply chain members,
cooperation and confrontation coexist. The key
feature of the assembly system is that the components
are complementary. In this context, two different
buy-back pricing mechanisms are studied, and the
influence of various parameters on the system
performance is analyzed. By comparison, a critical
condition about the proportion of profit is provided to
identify which mechanism is more beneficial to the
whole system. It is shown that the two mechanisms
will lead to the same system performance only when
the proportion of profit owned to the assembler is
equal to the number of members in the system.
The model in this paper is not without limitation.
In order to facilitate the analysis, only two extreme
cases are considered: The buy-back prices of all
components are determined by either the assembler
or the suppliers. In reality, the buy-back prices may
be set partly by the assembler and partly by the
suppliers. This is a very complicated case which may
be worth further exploration.
REFERENCES
Das D. (2017). An approach to improve supply chain profit
through buy-back contract with reference to a book
publishing firm. J. International Journal of Logistics
Systems and Management. 28(3), 338-354.
Donohue K L. (2000). Efficient supply contracts for fashion
goods with forecast updating and two production
modes. J. Management Science. 46(11), 1397-1411.
Emmos H, Gilbert S M. (1998). The role of returns policies
in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods.
J. Management Science. 44(2), 276-283.
Giri B C, Bardhan S. (2014). Coordinating a supply chain
with backup supplier through buyback contract under
supply disruption and uncertain demand. J.
International Journal of Systems Science: Operations
& Logistics. 1(4), 193-204.
Gong Q. (2008). Optimal buy-back contracts with
asymmetric information. J. International Journal of
Management and Marketing Research. 1(1), 23-47.
Hou Y, Sun X, Wang L. (2009). Buyback contract of supply
chain with supplierโ€™s sales effort. J. Science-
Technology and Management. 11(6), 21-23.
Lau H S, Lau A H L. (1999). Manufacturerโ€™s pricing
strategy and return policy for a single-period
commodity. J. European Journal of Operational
Research. 116(2). 291-304.
Padmanabhan V, Png I P L. (1995). Returns policies: Make
money by making good. J. Sloan Management Review.
37, 65-65.
Pasternack B A. (1985). Optimal pricing and return policies
for perishable commodities. J. Marketing Science. 4(2),
166-176.
Wang J, Wang Q, Sang S. (2008). Buyback policy in supply
chain under stochastic demand. J. Operations Research
and Management Science. 17(3), 164-167.
Wang Y, Gerchak Y. (2008). Capacity games in assembly
systems with uncertain demand. J. Manufacturing &
Service Operations Management. 5(3), 252-267.
Webster S, Weng Z K. (2000). A risk-free perishable item
returns policy. J. Manufacturing & Service Operations
Management. 2(1), 100-106.
Xiao Y, Wang X. (2008). Analysis on cordination and risk
sharing of supply chain based on buyback contract. J.
Control and Decision. 23(8), 905-909.
Xu T, Zhao Z, Nie Q. (2000). Study on profit incentive of
supplier and demander under buy-back contract. J.
Science & Technology Progress and Policy. 25(6), 48-
51.
Xu Z, Zhu D, Zhu W. (2008). Supply chain coordination
under buy-back contract with sales effort effects. J.
Systems Engineering - Theory & Practice. 2008(4), 1-
11.
Zhang Y, Donohue K, Cui T H. (2016). Contract
preferences and performance for the loss-averse
supplier: Buyback vs. revenue sharing. J. Management
Science. 62(6), 1734-1754.
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
144